Price Discrimination in International Trade: Empirical Evidence and Theory

Price Discrimination in International Trade: Empirical Evidence and Theory

by Sergii Meleshchuk

For a draft of the paper, see here.

Most models in contemporary international economics and macroeconomic literature make the assumption that sellers charge  all buyers the same price for the same good in a specific geographic market. In reality, however, a lot of business-to-business transactions occur in decentralized markets. Sellers of intermediate inputs have the power to vary prices across their buyers even if marginal costs of production are the same. In other words, sellers price-discriminate buyers. Anecdotally, quantity discounts (or second-degree price discrimination) are a common form of price discrimination in business-to-business transactions. However, welfare consequences of quantity discounts in general equilibrium models, as well as optimal policies in this setting remain largely understudied.

In an attempt to shed light on this matter, I make three contributions. First, I provide evidence of price discrimination in the transaction-level Colombian imports data. Second, I develop a tractable theoretical framework that embeds second-degree price discrimination into a widely-used class of gravity models in international trade and characterize optimal policies. Third, I calibrate the model using Colombian transaction-level data and use the calibrated model for welfare calculations.

My analysis proceeds in three steps. In the first step, I use Colombian transaction-level microdata to document a new set of stylized facts about price discrimination in international trade. The main goal of my empirical exercise is to estimate the supply-side elasticity of prices with respect to quantities of goods purchased. Using the unique richness of my data, I estimate this elasticity within narrowly defined exporting firm – good cells.

In my baseline specification, the elasticity of prices with respect to quantities is approximately -0.2.  That is, a 10% increase in quantity purchased reduces the price of a good produced by a particular exporter by 2%. The value of the estimated coefficient is robust across subsamples. These findings are consistent with second-degree price discrimination, a practice that allows firms to charge lower price when the volume of the purchase is higher. In a number of robustness checks, I rule out several competing explanations of the negative elasticity, such as non-classical measurement error and quality differentiation within narrowly defined exporter-goods categories.

In the second step, I rationalize these findings through the lens of a theoretical framework. Specifically,   I develop a tractable general equilibrium model featuring two sectors with heterogeneous firms producing nontradable final and tradable intermediate goods. Departing from previous trade models, I assume that firms in the final good sector can only purchase inputs directly from their producers, reselling of inputs is not allowed. Intermediate good producers do not observe the type (productivity) of their buyers, but they know the distribution of those types across buyers. This leads firms that produce intermediate inputs to construct an optimal price-quantity schedule for their output, rather than to quote a single price. Intermediate good producers decide to have a quantity-payment schedule that is equivalent to a two-part tariff: a sum of a fixed payment and a part that is a product of quantity, a constant marginal cost, and a constant markup. As a result, the unit price is decreasing in quantity.

In the third step, I calibrate the model using the microdata and quantify the welfare effects of optimal policies. The model has four main parameters. Two of them are calibrated using the distribution of imports by Colombian firms and the distribution of exports by foreign firms. The other two parameters are taken from the literature on the trade elasticity and the elasticity of substitution in consumption. Using these parameter values, I perform three exercises. First, I quantify the welfare losses driven by second-degree price discrimination. For the baseline calibration these losses are equal to 5% in terms of real consumption. Second, I quantify the ratio of welfare under the optimal policies relative to welfare in the benchmark case with no taxes. I find that in a small open economy, optimal policy can increase welfare by around 2% in settings with monopolistic competition and second-degree price discrimination. Third, I quantify the costs of a ‘policy mistake’ — a case in which firms use second-degree price discrimination but a policymaker adopts taxes that are optimal under monopolistic competition. In a small open economy this mistake can lead to welfare losses of around 0.7%.

 

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Optimal Spatial Reallocation

Optimal Spatial Reallocation

by Cecile Gaubert & Pablo Fajgelbaum (UCLA)

For a draft of the paper, see here.

The geographic distribution of economic activity within a country is an equilibrium object that balances agglomeration and congestion forces, and, by doing so, determines aggregate productivity and welfare. In this project, we ask: from the perspective of aggregate welfare, is this equilibrium efficient? Given an observed spatial equilibrium, what is the optimal spatial reallocation that leads to maximize welfare, and how can a federal planner implement this spatial reallocation?

See poster.

 

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Resource Misallocation in European Firms: The Role of Constraints, Firm Characteristics and Managerial Decisions

Resource Misallocation in European Firms: The Role of Constraints, Firm Characteristics and Managerial Decisions

by Yuriy Gorodnichenko

For a draft of the paper, see here.

The objective of this project was to study (mis)allocation of resources using a new survey from the European Investment Bank (EIB) and existing surveys run by the European Bank of Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). The main appeal of these surveys was information about various margins of adjustment as well as questionnaires consistent across a broad range of countries. The survey run the EBRD turned out to be less useful than originally anticipated: while the questionnaires are consistent across countries in a given wave of the survey, there were changes in the questionnaires across waves which limits the usefulness of the surveys for time series analyses. As a result, most of the work focused on the EIB survey.

Using the EIB data, we show that the dispersion in the use of resources among EU firms is large: about 50 percent wider than what has been found by previous studies for the US. We develop a simple dynamic theoretical framework of profit maximizing firms and estimate the dispersion of the marginal revenue product of capital (MRPK) and the marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) in the EU and individual countries. Our calculations suggest that reducing the EU dispersion in marginal revenue products to US levels – a change that would likely require many significant policy reforms – could increase the EU’s GDP by more than 20 percent.

We also use of Machado-Mata decomposition to construct counterfactual distributions of marginal revenue products for each country (Machado and Mata, 2005). This decomposition exercise helps us to understand better whether the observed variation in marginal revenue products is brought about by either (i) cross-country differences in firm characteristics or (ii) cross-country differences in how the business, institutional and policy environment guides the allocation of resources across heterogeneous firms, i.e. how regression coefficients on characteristics are “priced” into outcomes.

We find that cross-country variation in the dispersion of marginal revenue products is largely driven by differences in a country’s business, institutional and policy environment rather than by differences in firm characteristics per se. This result is important because it provides large-scale microeconomic evidence that institutions matter to explain the variation in marginal revenue products across EU firms. Using the example of Greece and Germany, we show that the dispersion of marginal revenue products is wider among firms in Greece than in Germany. However, the results suggest that if German firms were moved to Greece, they would not be more efficient than Greek firms: the dispersion of marginal revenue products for German firms would be even wider than the one actually observed in Greece. The Greek business, policy and institutional environment seems to be relatively ineffective in reducing the dispersion of marginal returns across firms. If Greek firms were to be moved to Germany instead, they would be almost as efficient than German firms: the standard deviation of this counterfactual distribution is much closer to the actual distribution of marginal revenue products in Germany. In other words, the German business, institutional and policy environment appears to help improve the equalization of returns across heterogeneous firms.

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

China and the SDR: Financial Globalization Through the Back Door

China and the SDR: Financial Globalization Through the Back Door

by Barry Eichengreen and Guangtao Xia

See paper.

The authors analyze the motives for China’s special drawing rights (SDRs) campaign. They argue that the campaign was a strategy used by the champions of financial liberalization in China to force the pace of reform. It was also a strategy with significant risks. Reaching agreement with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) on adding the renminbi to the currency basket required a judgment that the currency was freely usable for cross-border transactions. Achieving that agreement in turn required relaxing China’s comprehensive system of capital controls, and ensuring that a larger volume of cross-border capital flows was consistent with financial stability required domestic reforms to strengthen the financial system. But this was a strategy with limits. History is replete with examples of countries that have used external financial liberalization to create pressure for domestic reform. Unfortunately, the domestic reforms needed for the sustainability of those external measures do not always follow. External liberalization does not automatically weaken the influence of domestic interests resisting reform. When resistance is intense, the liberalization of cross-border financial flows can remain out in front of accompanying reforms of domestic financial governance and regulation. The result in this case can be volatile capital movements with destabilizing financial consequences, which is what China experienced in 2015.

 

Topics

Capital flows

Initiatives

Financial Globalization

Immersion Therapy

Immersion Therapy

by Noam Yutchman

As of 2015, 330,000 Mainland Chinese students attended U.S. universities, accounting for 31.5% of the international student body. What are the consequences of immersion in a foreign society on students studying away from home? In particular, what are the effects of immersion in a democratic society on students brought up under an authoritarian regime? In this project we study several dimensions of the effects of exposure to U.S. institutions on Chinese students’ political attitudes and behavior. We first aim to document the evolution of students’ views over time. Theoretically, exposure to the U.S. might lead Chinese students’ attitudes to become more politically liberal; however, it might lead to ideological “backlash” and greater political conservatism. It is important to note that students studying abroad have very different incentives to assimilate from long-term migrants: around 70-80% of Chinese students return home, so assimilation into U.S. society might be socially costly in the long run. We also plan to examine the role of social interactions in shaping political views among Chinese students in the U.S. Social networks will shape the information sets of students and also determine a range of incentives to access particular information and express particular views. Finally, we plan to conduct an experiment on the effects of early access to previously inaccessible news media on Chinese students’ experiences in the U.S. Working with partners in the media sector (e.g., the New York Times’ Asia Office), we plan to offer free access to the New York Times to a random subset of students whom we study.

 

Topics

Development, Education

Initiatives

International Trade & Development, International Business Education