Indian Demonetization & Real Effects

Indian Demonetization & Real Effects

by Mauricio Ulate, Rupal Kamdar and Walker Ray

On November 8, 2016, India stopped accepting all 500 and 1,000 rupee (approximately 7 and 15 dollars) notes, its two largest bills, as legal tender. This removed about 86% of cash in circulation. New 500 and 2,000 rupee notes were eventually issued, but the process of printing them and getting them distributed to the states took longer than anticipated. Around 98% of transactions in India occur in cash, so demonetization had profound consequences, with long queues at banks, low daily limits on withdrawals of the new bills, and certain sectors of the economy slowing down significantly. The move was done for motives related to counterfeiting and money laundering and, as such, was unrelated to the state of the Indian macro-economy. This is why it could serve as a natural experiment to study the real effects of monetary shocks, price rigidities and relative substitution patterns following a liquidity crunch. This project intends to use disaggregated data on prices and quantities of different consumption categories across regions in India to study these interesting topics. Preliminary results on the prices of agricultural goods seem to indicate that prices respond strongly and somewhat persistently to demonetization.

Topics

Development, Capital flows

Initiatives

International Trade & Development, Financial Globalization

Measuring Imperfect Competition in Product and Labor Markets: An Empirical Analysis using Plant Level Production Data

Measuring Imperfect Competition in Product and Labor Markets: An Empirical Analysis using Plant Level Production Data

by Roman Zarate & Dario Tortarolo

For a draft of the paper, see here.

In this paper, we develop a simple theoretical model that allows us to disentangle empirically the extent of imperfect competition in product and labor markets using plant-level production data.

The model assumes profit-maximizing producers that face upward-sloping labor supply and downward-sloping product demand curves. We derive a reduced-form formula for the ratio between markdowns and markups based on De Loecker and Warzynski (2012). We use production function estimation techniques to estimate output elasticities and construct a measure of combined market power at the firm level. We proceed to separate product and labor market power by estimating firm-level residual labor supply elasticities instrumenting wages with intermediate inputs. The exclusion restriction implies that shifts in the labor supply are not correlated with changes in the use of intermediate inputs. Our results suggest that both markets exhibit imperfect competition, but variation across industries is driven by the ease of firms to set prices above marginal costs rather than wages below the marginal revenue productivity of labor.

On average, manufacturing plants charge prices 78% higher than marginal costs and pay wages 11% less than the marginal revenue productivity of labor. We find a negative correlation between product and labor market power and more elastic labor supply curves for unskilled workers. Moreover, we obtain a positive correlation between firms’ product market power and productivity, size and exporter status, and a negative correlation of these measures with labor market power.

In the last part, we estimate the relative gains of eliminating market power dispersion on allocative efficiency using the model developed by Hsieh and Klenow (2009). We find that market power dispersion in product markets is more important on TFP than labor market power, and that the negative correlation between the two measures of market power corrects in 7% the economic distortion derived from market power dispersion.

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Geography & Supply Chain Organization

Geography & Supply Chain Organization

by Piyus Panigrahi

Liberalized mobility of goods and services across regions within a country gives rise to greater integration of markets for products. This results in these products being manufactured by more productive firms using a more efficient set of inputs, thereby increasing aggregate productivity of an economy. What role does geography play in the intra-national organization of supply chains? How can one quantify the micro-level implications of reduction in geographic barriers on firm-to-firm trade within and between regions? This project attempts to answer this question by developing a framework that incorporates the role of geographic barriers in the endogenous formation of supply chains and consequences thereof. In addition, such a framework for intra-national trade allows for rigorous analysis of both aggregate and micro-level implications of policy experiments. As a proof of concept, it will then be used to study the quantitative implications of region-based tax regime changes in a federal structure of government as is the case in India.

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Price Discrimination in International Trade: Empirical Evidence and Theory

Price Discrimination in International Trade: Empirical Evidence and Theory

by Sergii Meleshchuk

For a draft of the paper, see here.

Most models in contemporary international economics and macroeconomic literature make the assumption that sellers charge  all buyers the same price for the same good in a specific geographic market. In reality, however, a lot of business-to-business transactions occur in decentralized markets. Sellers of intermediate inputs have the power to vary prices across their buyers even if marginal costs of production are the same. In other words, sellers price-discriminate buyers. Anecdotally, quantity discounts (or second-degree price discrimination) are a common form of price discrimination in business-to-business transactions. However, welfare consequences of quantity discounts in general equilibrium models, as well as optimal policies in this setting remain largely understudied.

In an attempt to shed light on this matter, I make three contributions. First, I provide evidence of price discrimination in the transaction-level Colombian imports data. Second, I develop a tractable theoretical framework that embeds second-degree price discrimination into a widely-used class of gravity models in international trade and characterize optimal policies. Third, I calibrate the model using Colombian transaction-level data and use the calibrated model for welfare calculations.

My analysis proceeds in three steps. In the first step, I use Colombian transaction-level microdata to document a new set of stylized facts about price discrimination in international trade. The main goal of my empirical exercise is to estimate the supply-side elasticity of prices with respect to quantities of goods purchased. Using the unique richness of my data, I estimate this elasticity within narrowly defined exporting firm – good cells.

In my baseline specification, the elasticity of prices with respect to quantities is approximately -0.2.  That is, a 10% increase in quantity purchased reduces the price of a good produced by a particular exporter by 2%. The value of the estimated coefficient is robust across subsamples. These findings are consistent with second-degree price discrimination, a practice that allows firms to charge lower price when the volume of the purchase is higher. In a number of robustness checks, I rule out several competing explanations of the negative elasticity, such as non-classical measurement error and quality differentiation within narrowly defined exporter-goods categories.

In the second step, I rationalize these findings through the lens of a theoretical framework. Specifically,   I develop a tractable general equilibrium model featuring two sectors with heterogeneous firms producing nontradable final and tradable intermediate goods. Departing from previous trade models, I assume that firms in the final good sector can only purchase inputs directly from their producers, reselling of inputs is not allowed. Intermediate good producers do not observe the type (productivity) of their buyers, but they know the distribution of those types across buyers. This leads firms that produce intermediate inputs to construct an optimal price-quantity schedule for their output, rather than to quote a single price. Intermediate good producers decide to have a quantity-payment schedule that is equivalent to a two-part tariff: a sum of a fixed payment and a part that is a product of quantity, a constant marginal cost, and a constant markup. As a result, the unit price is decreasing in quantity.

In the third step, I calibrate the model using the microdata and quantify the welfare effects of optimal policies. The model has four main parameters. Two of them are calibrated using the distribution of imports by Colombian firms and the distribution of exports by foreign firms. The other two parameters are taken from the literature on the trade elasticity and the elasticity of substitution in consumption. Using these parameter values, I perform three exercises. First, I quantify the welfare losses driven by second-degree price discrimination. For the baseline calibration these losses are equal to 5% in terms of real consumption. Second, I quantify the ratio of welfare under the optimal policies relative to welfare in the benchmark case with no taxes. I find that in a small open economy, optimal policy can increase welfare by around 2% in settings with monopolistic competition and second-degree price discrimination. Third, I quantify the costs of a ‘policy mistake’ — a case in which firms use second-degree price discrimination but a policymaker adopts taxes that are optimal under monopolistic competition. In a small open economy this mistake can lead to welfare losses of around 0.7%.

 

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Optimal Spatial Reallocation

Optimal Spatial Reallocation

by Cecile Gaubert & Pablo Fajgelbaum (UCLA)

For a draft of the paper, see here.

The geographic distribution of economic activity within a country is an equilibrium object that balances agglomeration and congestion forces, and, by doing so, determines aggregate productivity and welfare. In this project, we ask: from the perspective of aggregate welfare, is this equilibrium efficient? Given an observed spatial equilibrium, what is the optimal spatial reallocation that leads to maximize welfare, and how can a federal planner implement this spatial reallocation?

See poster.

 

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Resource Misallocation in European Firms: The Role of Constraints, Firm Characteristics and Managerial Decisions

Resource Misallocation in European Firms: The Role of Constraints, Firm Characteristics and Managerial Decisions

by Yuriy Gorodnichenko

For a draft of the paper, see here.

The objective of this project was to study (mis)allocation of resources using a new survey from the European Investment Bank (EIB) and existing surveys run by the European Bank of Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). The main appeal of these surveys was information about various margins of adjustment as well as questionnaires consistent across a broad range of countries. The survey run the EBRD turned out to be less useful than originally anticipated: while the questionnaires are consistent across countries in a given wave of the survey, there were changes in the questionnaires across waves which limits the usefulness of the surveys for time series analyses. As a result, most of the work focused on the EIB survey.

Using the EIB data, we show that the dispersion in the use of resources among EU firms is large: about 50 percent wider than what has been found by previous studies for the US. We develop a simple dynamic theoretical framework of profit maximizing firms and estimate the dispersion of the marginal revenue product of capital (MRPK) and the marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) in the EU and individual countries. Our calculations suggest that reducing the EU dispersion in marginal revenue products to US levels – a change that would likely require many significant policy reforms – could increase the EU’s GDP by more than 20 percent.

We also use of Machado-Mata decomposition to construct counterfactual distributions of marginal revenue products for each country (Machado and Mata, 2005). This decomposition exercise helps us to understand better whether the observed variation in marginal revenue products is brought about by either (i) cross-country differences in firm characteristics or (ii) cross-country differences in how the business, institutional and policy environment guides the allocation of resources across heterogeneous firms, i.e. how regression coefficients on characteristics are “priced” into outcomes.

We find that cross-country variation in the dispersion of marginal revenue products is largely driven by differences in a country’s business, institutional and policy environment rather than by differences in firm characteristics per se. This result is important because it provides large-scale microeconomic evidence that institutions matter to explain the variation in marginal revenue products across EU firms. Using the example of Greece and Germany, we show that the dispersion of marginal revenue products is wider among firms in Greece than in Germany. However, the results suggest that if German firms were moved to Greece, they would not be more efficient than Greek firms: the dispersion of marginal revenue products for German firms would be even wider than the one actually observed in Greece. The Greek business, policy and institutional environment seems to be relatively ineffective in reducing the dispersion of marginal returns across firms. If Greek firms were to be moved to Germany instead, they would be almost as efficient than German firms: the standard deviation of this counterfactual distribution is much closer to the actual distribution of marginal revenue products in Germany. In other words, the German business, institutional and policy environment appears to help improve the equalization of returns across heterogeneous firms.

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development