The Renminbi as Global or Regional Currency

The Renminbi as Global or Regional Currency

By Barry Eichengreen (UC Berkeley) & Domenico Lombardi (CIGI)

Link to paper, forthcoming in Asian Economic Papers.

The project, undertaken jointly with Domenico Lombardi of CIGI (Canada), sought to analyze the Chinese renminbi’s prospects as a global and regional currency, the question being whether the renminbi is more likely to play a consequential international role globally or within Asia.  To this end, the following aspects of renminbi internationalization were analyzed.

a)      The weight on the renminbi as an anchor currency in the exchange rate baskets of different countries, following the methodology pioneered by Frankel and Wei.

b)      The geographic distribution of People’s Bank of China renminbi swap lines, following the methodology of Garcia-Hererro et al.

c)       The timing of announcements designating official renminbi clearing banks for different foreign financial centers.

d)      The geographic distribution of QFI and QFII foreign investor renminbi quotas.

e)      The role of the renminbi in the IMF’s SDR basket and Asia’s Chiang Mai Initiative Multilateralization.

f)       The role of political linkages and alliances in the reserve-composition decisions of central banks and governments.

The analysis did not definitively determine whether the renminbi’s future was as a global or regional currency, but it identified factors and influences on which the outcome is likely to turn.

Research papers in this stream were presented in the 2015-6 academic year to seminars and conferences at UC Berkeley (Center for Chinese Studies), Stanford University (Center for Asian Studies), Harvard University, the University of Malaysia (Jeffrey Chia Institute), and the Korea Development Institute.

Link to paper, forthcoming in Asian Economic Papers.

 

Topics

Capital flows, Architecture

Initiatives

Financial Globalization, International Financial Architecture

How Much Do Individual Firms Shape a Country’s Comparative Advantage?

How Much Do Individual Firms Shape a Country’s Comparative Advantage?

by Cecile Gaubert (UC Berkeley) & Oleg Itskhoki (Princeton)

Link to draft  paper.

Firms play a pivotal role in international trade. Much of exports is done by a small number of very large fi rms that enjoy substantial market shares in their markets across destination countries. One may thus conjecture that countries export not only the goods they are fundamentally good at producing, but also the goods that their individual firms happen to master to produce in an idiosyncratic way. As a consequence, if some of these individual firms disappeared, the country’s comparative advantage would be dramatically altered. Casual empiricism suggests that indeed individual firms play a central role in shaping country-level trade patterns: for example, the fate of Nokia in Finland or Intel in Costa Rica have shaped aggregate export patterns in these countries.

This paper contrasts such granular comparative advantage with the fundamental comparative advantage of a country, which we define as a sector-level characteristic stemming from technological differences or factor endowment differences across countries. In more formal terms, we ask to what extent the country’s comparative advantage is shaped by the high-mean sectoral productivity versus outstanding productivity draw(s) from an otherwise unremarkable mean-productivity distribution? Furthermore, can one identify which specific export sectors are `granular’?

By doing so, we revisit the fundamental questions in international trade: What goods do countries trade? What is the source of countries’ comparative advantage? The answers to these questions are interesting in themselves, even if the source of comparative advantage were not consequential for trade flows and welfare gains from trade. Furthermore, the knowledge of the specific source of comparative advantage is instrumental for our ability to predict changes in trade flows in response to a variety of shocks, such as reductions in trade costs and productivity changes across countries.

We propose a `granular’ multi-sector model of trade, which combines fundamental comparative advantage across sectors with granular comparative advantage due to outstanding productivity of individual rms. We develop a SMM-based estimation procedure, which takes full account of the general equilibrium model, and jointly estimate the fundamental and the granular forces using French micro-level data with information on fi rm domestic and export sales across manufacturing industries. The estimated granular model captures the salient features of micro-level heterogeneity across firms and industries, without relying on variation in model parameters across sectors. The estimated model implies that thirty percent of trade flows is explained by granular forces, and that sectors with the highest export shares are more likely to be of granular origin than sectors with average export shares. Extending the model to allow for firm-level productivity dynamics explains the majority of the change in the country’s comparative advantage over time. We further show that empirically measurable proxies of granularity have a substantial predictive ability for trade flows in the estimated model, even after controlling for fundamental comparative advantage of the sectors. Lastly, we show that the welfare gains from liberalizing a sector are shaped by the extent to which this sector is granular.

Photo source: www.linkhigher.com

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Appliance Adoption in Recently Electrified Rural Indian Villages

Appliance Adoption in Recently Electrified Rural Indian Villages

by Meredith Fowlie (Department of agricultural and Resource Economics, UC Berkeley) and Catherine Wolfram (Berkeley Haas)

See the USAID report on this project.

Nearly all of the growth in energy demand, fossil fuel use, associated local pollution, and greenhouse gas emissions is forecast to come from the developing world, yet we know very little about how energy is used in developing countries. The Berkeley professors doing this project are involved with a Berkeley-based startup, Gram Power, which provides solar power to rural villages in India using a smart microgrid technology that includes prepaid smart meters and grid monitoring devices. Because the provider is using smart meters and because and the team includes engineers, it is possible to analyze minute-by-minute electricity usage and infer the type of appliance the household is using at the time .The project will fund appliances (e.g., light bulbs) to the newly connected households. Households will be randomly selected to receive either a low efficiency version (e.g., compact fluorescent) or a high efficiency version (e.g., LED). The project will analyze households’ decisions about how much to use the different appliances. If households randomly selected to receive the high efficiency versions use them for more hours per week, this would be concrete, experimentally derived evidence of a rebound effect. Debates about how large the rebound effect is likely to be are central to policy discussions about the role of energy efficiency in mitigating climate change. To date, there is very little empirical evidence on the rebound effect, and none from the developing world.

Photo source: https://flic.kr/p/Deit6

 

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Cross-Border Acquisitions and Labor Regulations

Cross-Border Acquisitions and Labor Regulations

by Ross Levine, Chen Lin and Beibei Shen

For draft of the paper, see here.

Do labor regulations influence the reaction of stock markets and firm profitability to cross-border acquisitions? Levine, Lin and Shen discover that acquiring firms enjoy smaller abnormal stock returns and profits when target firms are in countries with stronger labor protection regulations, i.e., in countries where laws, regulations, and policies increase the costs to firms of adjusting their workforces. These effects are especially pronounced when the target firm is in a labor-intensive or high labor-volatility industry. Consistent with labor regulations shaping the success of cross-border deals, Levine, Lin and Shen find that firms make fewer and smaller cross-border acquisitions into countries with strong labor regulations.

See poster.

Topics

Capital flows

Initiatives

Financial Globalization

Peer Effects in the Demand for Energy in Mexico

Peer Effects in the Demand for Energy in Mexico

by Lucas Davis (Berkeley- Haas)

From 2009–2012, Mexico implemented a national energy-efficiency program that replaced 1.9 million aging refrigerators and air conditioners with modern, efficient models.  This research will study whether participation in the program by a neighbor made households more likely to participate or otherwise reduce their electricity usage.  Peer effects in energy-efficiency decisions are potentially very important, yet there are no credible empirical estimates of their presence or magnitude.  Mexico’s appliance replacement program is an ideal setting for evaluating these types of peer effects.  It was conducted at a huge scale, making it particularly worthy of careful evaluation.  Though exceptional in size, its design is typical of energy-efficiency programs in many countries, so findings may be of broad interest.  Because participation was limited to households with historic monthly electricity consumption above a set threshold, this project can compare the neighbors of households who were barely eligible to the neighbors of households who were barely ineligible. This allows for highly credible and transparent measurement of peer effects. Preliminary evidence finds substantial peer effects concentrated within 1-2 months from the time of participation. The timing and size of the effect suggest that program awareness may be particiularly important in affecting energy-efficiency program participation.

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development

Does Peer Use Influence Adoption of Efficient Cookstoves? Evidence from a randomized controlled trial in Uganda

Does Peer Use Influence Adoption of Efficient Cookstoves? Evidence from a randomized controlled trial in Uganda

by David Levine (Berkeley Haas)

Link to paper

This paper examines the effect of peer usage on consumer demand for efficient cookstoves with a randomized controlled trial in rural Uganda. It test if the neighbors of buyers who ordered and received a stove are more likely to purchase an efficient cookstove than the neighbors of buyers who ordered but have not yet received a stove. The paper finds that neighbors of buyers who have experience with the stove are not detectably more likely to purchase a stove than neighbors of buyers who have not yet received their stove. It does find evidence of peer effects in opinions about efficient cookstoves. Knowing that a prominent member of the community has the efficient stove predicts 17–22 percentage points higher odds of strongly favoring the stove. But this more favorable opinion seemingly has no impact on purchase decisions.

The paper, with Andrew Simons, Theresa Beltramo and Garrick Blalock, is forthcomingin  Health Communications, 20, 2015: 55–66.

Photo source: https://flic.kr/p/6CKP1J

Topics

Development

Initiatives

International Trade & Development